“It is not easy for a free community to organize for war,” wrote John Maynard Keynes in 1940.1 He was commenting on something very obvious: people do not like to be told what to do. Keynes was frustrated by the inability of political leaders to lucidly explain to the public what needed to be done. Resources had to be allocated to the war effort and, after that, a clear statement of how the remainder would be shared amongst the public had to be made. Instead, politicians were glossing over both issues with superlatives and no clear plan. Writing, as I am in March 2020, as politicians announce today what they claimed was unthinkable just yesterday (and I mean that literally), I get where Keynes is coming from even if the magnitude of the problem seems comfortably lower.
Keynes was particularly concerned that the decisions that needed to be made were numerous and inter-related with one another.
Is it better that the War Office should have a large reserve of uniforms in stock or that the cloth should be exported to increase the Treasury’s reserve of foreign currency? Is it better to employ our shipyards to build warships or merchant-men? Is it better that a 20-year-old agricultural worker should be left on the farm or taken into the army?
He pointed out the obvious. A start was to think about which margin to fix — the standard of civilian life or the war effort — leaving the other as the residual. This had to be decided one way or the other. In our present conundrum, when asked, people would surely say that we should fight the pandemic first and adjust the rest. The fact that, in 1940, Keynes was pointing out that it was not obvious what Britain had decided should give us pause.
It is for this reason that having a clear and resolved approach to holding the line on health is warranted. In its absence we may have a situation where we end up at a point where we have the opportunity to improve the economy and public health. At that point, political leaders have tried to limit the damage on the economy but, in the process, have failed to contain the virus and, thus, have chosen a lower point with regard to public health. That situation calls for strong measures to move back to what might be possible.
It is a striking fact that even the most market-loving, capitalist nations quickly abandoned the decentralized process of allocating resources in the face of World War II. To be sure, no one expected the military to use markets to decide where to deploy troops and equipment but the fact that the rest of the economy moved to a war footing in this way is useful to reflect upon. In particular, for the most part, even though they may have flirted for a day with relying on strong advice to citizens, governments in the COVID-19 pandemic realized that was insufficient to their ends and ended up with strict and, in some cases, very strictly enforced policies. More authoritarian regimes were a little quicker to act initially, but the lag between could be measured in days for most countries.
Economists claim that markets are the most efficient way of allocating resources and solving the age-old problem of who gets what if there isn’t enough to go around. To be sure, markets are quite amazing in this regard and every economist has their moment of wonder that it works. Here is Thomas Schelling:
Most people, whether they drive their own taxis or manage continent-wide airlines, are expected to know very little about the whole economy and the way it works. They know the prices of the things they buy and sell, the interest rates at which they lend and borrow, and something about the pertinent alternatives to the ways they are currently earning their living or running their business or spending their money. The dairy farmer doesn’t need to know how many people eat butter and how far away they are, how many other people raise cows, how many babies drink milk, or whether more money is spent on beer than on milk. What he needs to know is the prices of different feeds, the characteristics of different cows, the different prices farmers are getting for milk according to its butter fat content, the relative costs of hired labor and electrical machinery, and what his net earnings might be if he sold his cows and raised pigs instead or sold his farm and took the best job for which he’s qualified in some city he is willing to live in.
Somehow all of the activities seem to get coordinated. There’s a taxi to get you to the airport. There’s butter and cheese for lunch on the airplane. There are refineries to make the airplane fuel and trucks to transport it, cement for the runways, electricity for the escalators, and, most important of all, passengers who want to fly where the airplanes are going.2
It is a miracle and we should appreciate it as such. The problem is that it doesn’t always get the job done.
When the job to be done is urgent and resources need to be reallocated quickly, the system can gum up. The issue is not markets per se but the problems of relying on a decentralized process whereby everyone allocates the resources they control on the basis of their own information and preferences. Instead, the problem we face in a time of war (or pandemic) is that resources, currently controlled by individuals, need to all be applied to a new end and the task of convincing everyone to choose to do so is unlikely to work out well.
This notion was captured in a 1990 paper by economists Patrick Bolton and Joe Farrell.3 Imagine a situation where we need one factory to produce face masks and another to produce ventilators but we don’t know which will be able to do each task at the lowest cost. In a market economy, each factory owner might look at the situation and try to work out what to do. One option is that they both jump in and start producing the product they think they will provide most efficiently. They retool for that purpose but there is a chance that they will end up both choosing the same thing and we will end up with too many face masks and too few ventilators or vice versa. Another option is to wait and see what the other factory chooses to do and then do the opposite. But in this world, we have both factories waiting to see what happens and there is a consequent delay. In other words, decentralization either will not get the job done or it will cause it to be delayed.
The alternative is for someone to choose who does what. This is the role of central planning. This prevents both duplication and delay but opens up another problem: the government may make the wrong choice. They may end up producing both goods at a higher cost than otherwise. Suffice it to say, at times of crisis we do not let the perfect be the enemy of the good and so comfortably resort to centralized resource allocation and wear the potential productive inefficiency.4
There are three areas where in the COVID-19 pandemic, market processes were abandoned in favor of planning. These included the mobilization of resources to dramatically expand health care system capacity, the institution of price controls for certain important goods and services and the use of blanket restrictions on movement of people. Each of these will be discussed in turn.
The initial responses from governments to the pandemic were to institute progressively strong forms of social distancing in the hope of reducing R0 (the number of people infected people themselves infect). Those responses had the goal of what came to be known as ‘flattening the curve.’ In a scenario where this needs to be done once, this involved a scenario such as depicted in Figure 3-1. The task was not so much as to reduce the total number who became infected but to spread them out over time to economize on health care system resources.
Figure 3-1: Flattening the Curve
The problem was determining how flat we needed to go. The flatter the goal, the harder it is to achieve and, moreover, the greater are the consequent costs of prolonged economic harm, social isolation, and the possibilities that there could be a subsequent re-emergence of the pandemic causing us to do it over again.
The health care system capacity is likely way lower than the diagram is showing beyond what flattening the curve can actually achieve. This differs by country. Japan has 13 beds per capita while the United States has under 3 beds per capita. And this is just a guide. There were large national differences in key inputs such as ICU beds, ventilators, hospital protective equipment and health care workers. Nonetheless, in most cases, it was clear that policies aimed at reducing R0 had happened too late to prevent health care system capacity from being reached. In Italy, doctors were having to perform heart-breaking triage operations determining which patients would get scarce resources. This was beyond their usual option of providing those resources even when they had a low probability of being required. From an economics perspective, health care resources were going to have demand that far outstripped supply. What is more, there was no prospect or desire to use higher prices to deal with the shortage. As Keynes noted for World War II, a plan for rationing was required but no plan was being formulated.
Given this, it is somewhat surprising that more was not being done to dramatically increase the capacity of the health care system. It is a policy option that both reduces the cost of overwhelmed capacity and reduces the amount of flatness of the curve and its associated costs. To be sure, in March 2020, calls were being made for more ventilators and other equipment.5 But countries had not done what China had done earlier in Wuhan by building entirely new hospitals in just over a week. Everyone marvelled at this. I heard: “wow, we can’t do that.” And this was mostly from the health care industry whose basic message for years is how hard it is to provide more. They have had expansion beaten out of them by years of a scarcity mindset.
While flattening the curve could take place and reduce the required capacity expansion, what was required was to surf the curve (see Figure 3-2). In this situation, health care system capacity would be temporarily expanded so as to cover the unflattened portion of the curve.
Figure 3-2: Surfing the Curve
Building out that capacity requires a new mindset and it requires it quickly. The nature of the problem was obvious on the ground. This is Dr Daniel Horn (a physician at Massachusetts General Hospital in Boston):
In the face of a global shortage, American industries can step up and quickly produce ventilators. All week, I have been receiving text messages and emails that say things like “By the way, my company makes parts for G.E. ventilators. We just got a big order that we are pushing through as fast as we can.” The General Motors chief executive, Mary T. Barra, announced that G.M. was working closely with Ventec Life Systems, one of a few ventilator companies based in the U.S., to rapidly scale up production of their critically important respiratory products. My colleagues at the nation’s top hospitals are getting phone calls from tech leaders asking for ventilator specs.
Such stories give me hope. But we need the federal government, too. … We need a plan.6
Sound familiar? This is precisely the coordination problem as outlined by Bolton and Farrell. Hospitals alone cannot procure what they need. Some factories can make some parts better than others. And then there is the issue of which hospitals to send them too. There was no information present and, in the US, despite having the powers to do so, no central action was being taken.
This highlighted the need for a war-like resource allocation mindset. Someone needed to take control and, when it came to fast and rapid capacity of health care, most countries had an obvious candidate — the military. Mobile Army Surgical Hospital or M*A*S*H was not just a TV show but also a capability that armed forces needed. It just had to be moved to civilian ends. In some countries, this happened with the military preparing and/or building facilities in Switzerland, Colombia, the Netherlands, Italy and France. The US also redirected hospital ships to California and New York to handle patients with other conditions who might be pushed out of those systems.
The numbers involved, however, suggest that a more comprehensive and aggressive solution would likely be required. Not only military provision but also a means of diverting manufacturing effort to the cause. Much of this was lying idle due to social distancing. The need was for a centralized process to unlock that potential and ensure timely provision. In World War II, businesses quickly retooled for military production. The same would be required here. Moreover, there would likely be a need for additional health care workers. This too could be a mobilization effort (perhaps even supported by conscription). The good news is that those resources were idle. The better news was that, unlike in wartime, no one was asking those helping to kill others.
Hand sanitizer and toilet paper went first. Hand sanitizer made sense. It was a genuine surge in demand as people expected to use more, much more, of it and were advised to do so. Toilet paper came as a surprise. This was not just a surge in demand but hoarding. But why? As Justin Wolfers argued, showing that economists were unafraid to tell it like it is, “[o]nce they have more toilet paper, people aren’t going to poo more.”7 He saw it like a bank run. People saw that toilet paper supplies were dwindling and bought more because they were concerned about supplies down the track. This created a run on the product just like a bank run. Suffice it to say, as it turned out, toilet paper was back in the store after the initial rush before people found that they didn’t have a square to spare.8
Hand sanitizer and other products that might be subject to real shortages were another matter. One story involved a couple of entrepreneurs who bought up a huge supply of hand sanitizer right after the first US death on March 1.9 They had intended to sell their stock of 17,700 bottles at a large mark-up on Amazon. Before they could do so, Amazon cracked down preventing them and others from selling the items that were in high demand. Ebay followed suit. In the end, the bottles were donated to hospitals.
Price gouging is given an ugly name because, of course, it is associated with people taking advantage of shortages in times of crisis to make a profit. At normal times, we usually like high prices because they signal to others were demand is high and there are profitable opportunities to produce more. In other words, they are part of a market process for resource allocation. When we outlaw or otherwise try to provide a cap on prices, what we are doing is accepting a shortage.
As John Kenneth Galbraith, who headed up the US World War II office of price controls, noted, this is an acceptance of a ‘disequilibrium system’ where demand persistently outstrips supply. This meant that items subject to controls needed to be rationed. As Galbraith noted, the outrage at this process tended to involve surprising items (just as we saw with toilet paper):
[F]or some reason ceilings on fur coats inspired them to special anger. On several occasions I found myself contending with new colleagues (and once with a new administrator) who were enthusiastic about dropping price controls on fur coats. When they saw that this action would put a premium on high-priced coat manufacture, would draw materials (“trim”) away from cheaper lines, they soon reversed themselves. In doing so they adopted a position entirely consistent with a broad theoretical pattern for allocating resources and equalizing incentives. Of the existence of any such theoretical pattern they were totally unaware.10
Given this, it is instructive to consider why we happily resort to price controls in times of crisis.
The reason is that it may well do a better job at resource allocation. According to research by Piotr Dworczak, Scott Kominers and Mohammad Akbarpour,11 who we want to get hand sanitizer can be different from who the market will allocate it to. In particular, had the price gougers got their way, only the wealthy would have got their hands on it and, in the process, protected themselves and the people they interacted with from infection.12 But those are the very people who have the best access to health care, don’t live in more densely-populated neighborhoods, or who can easily work from home. What makes more social sense is for the poorer members of the community to be allocated the hand sanitizer. Price controls give them a fighting chance. What might even be better is directly allocating hand sanitizer supply according to where it can have the greatest impact.
Here is the calculation. If the R0 for COVID-19 is 2 then an infected person will cause 2 others to be infected. But it obscures the magnitude of the problem. Those 2 people will infect 2 more people and so on. After ten rounds of this that adds up to 1,024. (If R0 = 3, it is 59,049!) If one percent of those people die from the disease, one infected person has been responsible for 10 deaths. Suffice it to say, that puts mass shootings in perspective. It is no surprise we want to keep infected people isolated.
The problem is how to do that. For starters, you have to know you are infected and with COVID-19, as was already explained in Chapter 1, the majority of infected people don’t know it. Moreover, once you do know it, using claims such as I have just done that you might be responsible for between ten and six hundred deaths, means that being infected carries a social stigma. Laura Derksen and Joep van Oosterhout found this when examining the spread of AIDS in Africa.13 They found that when people were asked to opt for testing or AIDS-related care, there were few takers because people feared the stigma of being seen to be concerned. People have to be generally and publicly knowledgable about the social benefits of these actions otherwise they might choose to cover up symptoms fearing discrimination. If refusing to go out is seen as a cover, that may be a problem.
Ordinarily, if you were going to restrict movement of people, you would try and target the individuals both at risk and who are likely to be people with a higher individual-R0. For COVID-19, some physicians wondered if a more targeted approach could be achieved. For instance, as those over the age of 70 were more likely to require the higher end of health costs (including death) associated with the virus, would it be better to isolate them leaving the rest of the population to circulate?14 Doing this would greatly mitigate the economic costs from a broader policy.
The problem with targeting is that there are real doubts it would work. If a large proportion of those under 70 still become sick and need hospitalization, resources could still be overwhelmed. Moreover, with large numbers of infected younger people, we lack the people to support the elderly being isolated. As Alex Tabarrok agues, there are internal contradictions that may well render it impossible for a more ‘surgical’ approach to social distancing.15
Targeted policies are also hard to enforce. When there are restrictions on movement, it is very easy for the authorities to see whether people are moving or not. In their absence it is harder to tell and can require more resources.16 For these reasons, to deal with the costs associated with COVID-19 transmission, governments have opted for blanket policies akin to martial law in wartime or other times of emergency. These may be supported by penalties for violations but nothing like the type of taxes that economists would otherwise recommend so that exceptions can be made at the discretion of individual decision-makers willing to bear a taxation cost. Instead, a heavy-handed approach is used without much room for nuance.
At the time of writing, the length of time for social distancing has been of the order of a few weeks. What remains unknown is precisely how long it both needs to and can last. I leave that as an open question that may already be answered by the time you read this book.